Account for environmental externalities? We can do it.

I am pleased to report that my last post (“Renewables: it takes a portfolio”) received the most comments ever! In that post I discussed how to think about constructing a least-cost portfolio of thermal generation, storage, and demand response to complement renewables. In this followup, I would like to respond to attorney Dan Watkiss, who commented that “your economic analysis fails to account for environmental and social externalities — you’re not alone in this very serious flaw in current energy economic analysis.” He’s right. We need to include the environmental and social costs of energy production. What I’d like to do here is to expand my previous energy economic analysis to include environmental externalities. How can we account for the environmental cost of carbon dioxide emissions in designing a least-cost portfolio? I am now expanding “cost” to mean not just capital and operating costs but also the cost to our environment.

There is a simple fix, and it’s not new. It’s the idea of a price on carbon. As many economists have noted (see, for example, the extensive discussion by Professor Robert Stavins of Harvard), the most straightforward approach to pricing carbon is either a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade mechanism. In either case, a price is charged to the carbon emitter for the negative impact on the environment. Many countries now have a price on carbon, and Australia had a price on carbon from 2012 to 2014. In the case of a carbon tax, if we can estimate the marginal environmental cost of carbon dioxide emissions, then we can set a price on carbon emissions equal to this marginal environmental cost. In the short term, this forces fossil generators to pay the costs of polluting the environment. The higher their operating cost, the less competitive they are in the electricity market, the less electricity they’ll sell, and the less profit they will earn. In the long term, generators will be incentivized to invest in carbon-reduction technology, such as carbon capture and sequestration, or exit the industry.

Let’s more carefully compare the incentives provided by a price on carbon emissions versus not pricing emissions. First, on the demand side: without a price on carbon that reflects the underlying cost to the environment, we will tend to consume too many carbon intensive resources. Professors Severin Borenstein of the University of California, Berkeley, and Jim Bushnell of the University of California, Davis, have found that volumetric charges (per kWh prices) to consumers to recover the fixed costs of various policy measures will sometimes result in retail prices that are too high in US states such as California, but which are too low in several other US states. In locations where retail prices are too low to fully reflect the social cost of emissions, consumption can be expected to exceed socially optimal levels: people are using too much electricity compared to other fuels.  For example, if retail gas and electric prices do not correctly reflect emissions costs, then shifting from gas to electric heating in a coal-dominated electricity system might result in higher emissions, and higher overall costs considering capital, operating, and emissions costs than if retail prices correctly reflected the social cost of emissions.

On the supply side, the lack of a price on carbon will tend to result in an inefficient mix of generation: too much generation from resources that emit carbon dioxide, and too much capacity of such high emission resources.  Again, this means that the overall costs including capital, operating, and emissions will be higher than they should be. For a concrete example of the implications for generation dispatch, see exercise 7.2 in my “Locational Marginal Pricing” course (from slide 74 onward). With a price on carbon, market forces will tend to bring the industry toward the goal of minimizing overall capital, operating, and environmental costs.

However, the political reality is that governments are loathe to impose a price on carbon, particularly where the fossil fuel industry is influential. In Australia, for example, the Federal Liberal government’s net-zero mantra is “technology not taxes.” It is betting that as-yet-unknown advances in technology will get the country to net-zero by 2050, without any need for a price on carbon. And, perhaps even more importantly, without hurting the influential coal industry. Does this “technology not taxes” strategy, repeated by representatives of the Australian government, including Prime Minister Scott Morrison, stand up to scrutiny? Will it get Australia to net-zero without a price on carbon dioxide emissions?

The short answer is no. For one thing, the technologies will not be deployed without governmental incentives to build the technology or disincentives against emissions. It’s common sense—why would anyone invest any money in new technology that comes without any added profit unless they are forced to? (For a smart analysis of all the reasons why “technology without taxes” is unreasonable, see these articles by the Sydney Morning Herald’s Economics Editor Ross Gittins: Praying, Net zero, Masterpiece.)

Are there alternatives to a price on carbon to reduce emissions? Given the political difficulties of pricing carbon dioxide emissions in both Australia and the US, could a subsidy, such as the US Production Tax Credits (PTCs), do the job instead? Although PTCs and other subsidies worldwide have helped to spur technology that has reduced the costs of building renewables, subsidies simply cannot get the same results as a price on carbon. There are at least two reasons. First, electricity prices end up being too low, thus incentivizing greater consumption. This may also result in too little generation capacity overall, leading to supply adequacy problems. Second, the price advantage of the subsidy to renewables does not differentiate between the emissions levels of the other resources, causing the wrong mix of supply-side thermal resources. For example, coal and combined cycle gas generation see the same differential price effect given a subsidy on renewables, even though coal generation emits approximately twice as much carbon dioxide as combined cycle gas generation. This gives a relative advantage to coal compared to gas when looked at from the perspective of total capital, operational, and environmental costs. With the same differential price due to the renewable subsidies, there will be too much coal generation relative to natural gas generation.

Now let’s look at carbon sequestration, one of the technologies that will likely be needed to get us to net zero. The Liberal Australian government speaks as if the technology for carbon capture and sequestration is so cheap, or even free, that no governmental mandate or regulation is required to see it implemented. But, in fact, there are significant capital and operation costs for sequestration. Without a price on carbon, and without a regulatory mandate or subsidies, what would motivate a coal or gas fired power station to invest large sums to capture and sequester its carbon dioxide emissions? It is hard to see why any company would do so. Without a price on carbon, carbon capture and sequestration would require mandates or subsidies, or both, because its capital and operating expenses are very high.

Is there a drawback of such mandates and subsidies? Targeting mandates and subsidies to particular market segments will likely mean that cheaper options to decarbonize are overlooked. That is, when any government picks winners and losers, as it does when instituting mandates or offering subsidies, it likely makes the overall costs higher than they need to be. “Technology not taxes” will not result in minimizing overall capital, operating, and environmental costs.

Although the public discussion in Australia is not clear, subsidies to particular segments of the economy appear to be central to the Australian government’s decarbonization plans (see “Morrison’s Tricky Deal” and “Barnaby’s Billions”). Subsidies to one industry must be paid for somehow.  Where does the money come from? Subsidies must be funded out of taxes on other parts of the economy. So, the Australian government’s plan would be more properly described as “technology and taxes to fund subsidies.”  So, not only does “technology not taxes” not bring us toward minimizing overall costs, it also actually involves increased taxes.

A significant argument against pricing carbon is its disproportionate impact on low- and middle-income earners. How much more will low- and middle-income earners pay with a price on carbon than without? Will this affect their income negatively? Greenhouse emissions vary significantly by country and by person, and the accounting is complicated by the effect of carbon dioxide compared to other greenhouse gases, but we might estimate an average on the order of about 15 tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent per person per annum in Australia and the US. The marginal environmental cost of carbon dioxide emissions is contentious, but let’s consider an indicative value of US$50 per tonne. Charging for carbon dioxide emissions at this price would cost each person an average US$750. If this was in the form of a carbon tax, then the money would add to other taxes paid to the government.

How does that stack up compared to taxes and subsidies in typical income tax filings? As an example, the US “Earned Income Tax Credit” provides a per capita subsidy that ranges from around US$1500 to US$6700 per year per taxpayer for low- and moderate-income workers. To compensate low- and moderate-income earners for their roughly US$750 annual payments for carbon, we could increase their Earned Income Tax Credit by that amount. Analogous adjustments could be made in Australia and other countries.

I have discussed taxes, but what about technology? The “technology not taxes” mantra is half right. Technology is a necessary driver of carbon reduction, and we need to be aggressive about developing new low emissions technologies and improving energy efficiency. Moreover, some limited subsidies for early-stage technologies can be a great investment if they catalyze cost reductions for subsequent large-scale deployment. For example, the early effect of PTCs and Investment Tax Credits (ITCs) in the US, and other mechanisms such as feed-in tariffs elsewhere, have helped with research and development of renewables and with scaling up the renewables industry, contributing to the astonishing reductions in fabrication costs. This early-stage investment has helped to bring us to the point where the unsubsidized cost of new renewable electricity is now cheaper than fossil electricity. 

So Dan, in summary: we can account for environmental externalities in economic analyses. To do this we need a carbon price. If we can achieve that, then we can align everyone’s incentives toward decarbonization without a priori favoring one technology or another, or one industry over another. We need technology and a price on carbon.

About Ross Baldick

Electricity is an increasingly complex industry in the midst of transition to renewables and decarbonization. Using my 25 years’ experience as an engineer, policy analyst, and academic, I help my consulting clients think through their toughest technical challenges and formulate their best business strategies.
This entry was posted in commentary and tagged , . Bookmark the permalink.

2 Responses to Account for environmental externalities? We can do it.

  1. Matt Weldon says:

    Hello Dr. Baldick,
    I am glad to see you devote a piece to carbon/emission pricing. Though long advocated among economists, the huge political inertia says it can’t be mentioned too often. Climate change has always struck me as a ludicrous situation in which we have an abundance of technologies and solutions, know what we must do, but choose to leave our most powerful tool (the marketplace) working against us by accident rather than take action to make it work for us intentionally. We know the presumptions of the atmosphere and oceans being waste reservoirs of infinite capacity are wrong and we know $0 is the only wrong price for a commodity or material stream of any kind – but these remain fixtures of our current market design.

    I’m responding to your article to suggest that you review of what can more easily be done in TX and ERCOT with respect to pricing, than in other US jurisdiction, precisely because it is an intrastate network. We also already have a successful local emission pricing example. Austin Energy’s REACH (Reduce Emissions Affordably for Climate Health) program has been successfully leveraging the existing ERCOT wholesale market to reduce emissions cheaply since March 2020. AE has a couple self-imposed goals it pursues-1) stay in lower half of $/kWh costs within TX 2) constrain cost rise to be under2%. Within this guidance AE established a budget based (and power plant characteristics constrained) internal carbon price with a soft goal of reducing emissions by 30% relative to a business-as-usual operations model. Simply put– purchase power from the market when the power alternative is cleaner and relatively cheap vs a given AE power plant’s production. In 2020 AE delivered as much power as it did in 2019, but with ~ 30% fewer emissions (essentially running the FPP less) and the forfeited revenue cost was low at ~ $3.30/tonne CO2. This price may be compared to Social Cost of Carbon estimates ($135-$5500/tonne) or existing US federal CCS subsidies of $50/tonne. This program demonstrates all the positive benefits of a more rational valuation of emissions and shows positive effects on electric market operations – better pricing for power at all times, coal is suppressed first (TX produces 3% of nation’s coal) which benefits all power substitute sources (NG – TX produces 85%, nuclear, winds, solar), and in addition to reducing GHG emissions/MWh from ERCOT also immediately reduces primary pollutants. All benefits flow to TX and the cost of the program is so low than no one notices.

    I’ll send a separate Email with more specific information on REACH.

    • Ross Baldick says:

      Thank you for your comment.
      You suggest that Austin Energy’s REACH program has reduced carbon dioxide emissions in ERCOT.
      However, Austin Energy’s 2021 report on REACH, available at https://www.austintexas.gov/edims/document.cfm?id=371350,
      appears to only mention Austin Energy carbon dioxide emissions from Austin Energy’s ownership share in Fayette Power Plant. Austin Energy’s report on REACH does not make any statement about the effect of REACH on overall carbon dioxide emissions in ERCOT. In fact, the net change in overall emissions in ERCOT is no better than half the change in emissions from Austin Energy’s share of Fayette alone and the net change could be significantly less than half the change.

      In particular, when Fayette production is displaced by other fossil generation in ERCOT, the other generation will also emit carbon dioxide. In the best case for net carbon dioxide emissions, combined-cycle gas turbine generation would displace Fayette production, resulting in a net decrease in emissions equal to about half of Fayette’s emissions. However, even though the adjustment to the Fayette offer price under REACH is designed to result in a Fayette offer that is higher than the offer price of a combined-cycle, if there is other available coal generation at a lower offer price then that other coal generation will displace Austin Energy’s share of Fayette. This other coal generation could potentially come from, for example, the coal units at the WA Parish Power Plant, the Limestone Power Plant, or indeed from the Lower Colorado River Authority’s share of Fayette.

      Austin Energy’s REACH program is akin to a state or country importing an energy intensive product. Displacing local production by imports does not necessarily change the overall emissions although it can reduce emissions within that state or country. Similarly, the REACH program has reduced Austin Energy’s own carbon dioxide emissions, but overall carbon dioxide emissions in ERCOT have changed by significantly less. This is definitely in the right direction and should be lauded, but also points to the importance of a broad-based price on carbon across multiple industries and regions. I hope that Austin Energy’s stance on carbon dioxide emissions will contribute to support for broader-based carbon pricing.

What's on your mind?

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.